177x Filetype PDF File size 0.29 MB Source: web.econ.ku.dk
Chapter 16 Money in macroeconomics Moneybuysgoodsandgoodsbuymoney;butgoodsdonotbuygoods. Robert W. Clower (1967). Up to now we have put monetary issues aside. The implicit assumption has been that the exchange of goods and services in the market economy can be carried out without friction as mere intra- or intertemporal barter. This is, of course, not realistic. At best it can provide an acceptable approximation to reality only for a limited set of macroeconomic issues. We now turn to models in which there is a demand for money. We thus turn to monetary theory, that is, the study of causes and consequences of the fact that a large part of the exchange of goods and services in the real world is mediated through the use of money. 16.1 What is money? 16.1.1 The concept of money In economics money is de ned as an asset (a store of value) which functions as a generally accepted medium of exchange, i.e., it can be used directly to buy any good o¤ered for sale in the economy. A note of IOU (a bill of exchange) may also be a medium of exchange, but it is not generally accepted and is therefore 1 not money. Moreover, the extent to which an IOU is acceptable in exchange depends on the general state in the economy. In contrast, money is characterized by being a fully liquid asset. An asset is fully liquid if it can be used directly, instantly, and without any extra costs or restrictions to make payments. 1Generally accepted mediums of exchange are also called means of payment. 645 646 CHAPTER16. MONEYINMACROECONOMICS Figure 16.1: No direct exchange possible. A medium of exchange, here good 2, solves the problem (details in text). Generally, liquidity should be conceived as a matter of degree so that an asset has a higher or lower degree of liquidity depending on the extent to which it can easily be exchanged for money. By easilywe mean immediately, conveniently, and cheaply. So an assets liquidity is the ease with which the asset can be converted into money or be used directly for making payments. Where to draw the line betweenmoneyandnon-moneyassetsdependsonwhatisappropriatefor the problem at hand. In the list below of di¤erent monetary aggregates (Section 16.2), M corresponds most closely to the traditional de nition of money. De ned 1 as currency in circulation plus demand deposits held by the non-bank public in commercial banks, M embraces all under normal circumstancesfully liquid 1 assets in the hands of the non-bank public. Thereason that a market economy uses money is that money facilitates trade enormously, therebyreducingtransactioncosts. Moneyhelpsaneconomytoavoid the need for a double coincidence of wants. The classical way of illustrating this is by the exchange triangle in Fig. 16.1. The individuals A, B, and C are endowed with one unit of the goods 1, 3, and 2, respectively. But A, B, and C want to consume 3, 2, and 1, respectively. Thus, no direct exchange is possible between two individuals each wanting to consume the others good. There is a lack of double coincidence of wants. The problem can be solved by indirect exchange where A exchanges good 1 for good 2 with C and then, in the next step, uses good 2 in an exchange for good 3 with B. Here good 2 serves as a medium of exchange. If good 2 becomes widely used and accepted as a medium of exchange, it is money. Extending the example to a situation with n goods, we have that exchange without money (i.e., barter) requires n(n 1)=2 markets (trading spots). Exchange with money, in the form of modern paper money, requires only n markets. c Groth, Lecture notes in macroeconomics, (mimeo) 2015. 16.1. What is money? 647 16.1.2 Historical remarks In the past, ordinary commodities, such as seashells, rice, cocoa, precious metals etc., served as money. That is, commodities that were easily divisible, handy to carry, immutable, and involved low costs of storage and transportation could end up being used as money. This form of money is called commodity money. Applying ordinary goods as a medium of exchange is costly, however, because these goods have alternative uses. A more e¢ cient way to trade is by using currency, i.e., coins and notes in circulation with little or no intrinsic value, or pieces of paper, checks, representing claims on such currency. Regulation by a central authority (the state or the central bank) has been of key importance in bringing about this transition into the modern payment system. Coins, notes, pieces of paper like checks, and electronic signals from smart phones to accounts in a bank have no intrinsic value. Yet they may be generally accepted media of exchange, in which case we refer to them as paper money. By having these pieces of paper circulating and the real goods moving only once, from initial producer to nal consumer, the trading costs in terms of time and e¤ort are minimized. In the industrialized countries these paper monies were in the last third of the nineteenth century and until the outbreak of the First World War backed through the gold standard. And under the Bretton-Woods agreement, 1947-71, the currencies of the developed Western countries outside the United States were convertible into US dollars at a xed exchange rate (or rather an exchange rate which is adjustable only under speci c circumstances); and US dollar reserves of these countries were (in principle) convertible into gold by the United States at a xed price (though in practice with some discouragement from the United States). This indirect gold-exchange standard broke down in 1971-73, and nowadays money in most countries is unbacked paper money (including electronic entries in banksaccounts). This feature of modern money makes its valuation very di¤erent from that of other assets. A piece of paper money in a modern payments system has no worth at all to an individual unless she expects other economic agents to value it in the next instant. There is an inherent circularity in the acceptance of money. Hence the viability of such a paper money system is very much dependent on adequate juridical institutions as well as con dence in the ability and willingness of the government and central bank to conduct policies that sustain the purchasing power of the currency. One elementary juridical institution is that of legal tender, a status which is conferred to certain kinds of money. An example is the law that a money debt can always be settled by currency and a tax always be paid by currency. A medium of exchange whose market value derives entirely from its legal tender status is called at money c Groth, Lecture notes in macroeconomics, (mimeo) 2015. 648 CHAPTER16. MONEYINMACROECONOMICS (because the value exists through at, a rulers declaration). In view of the absence of intrinsic value, maintaining the exchange value of at money over time, that is, avoiding high or uctuating ination, is one of the central tasks of monetary policy. 16.1.3 The functions of money The following three functions are sometimes considered to be the de nitional characteristics of money: 1. It is a generally accepted medium of exchange. 2. It is a store of value. 3. It serves as a unit of account in which prices are quoted and books kept (the numeraire). On can argue, however, that the last function is on a di¤erent footing com- pared to the two others. Thus, we should make a distinction between the func- tions that money necessarily performs, according to our de nition above, and the functions that money usually performs. Property 1 and 2 certainly belong to the essential characteristics of money. By its role as a device for making transactions money helps an economy to avoid the need for a double coincidence of wants. In order to perform this role, money must be a store of value, i.e., a device that transfers and maintains value over time. The reason that people are willing to exchange their goods for pieces of paper is exactly that these can later be used to purchase other goods. As a store of value, however, money is dominated by other stores of value such as bonds and shares that pay a higher rate of return. Whennevertheless there is a demand for money, it is due to the liquidity of this store of value, that is, its service as a generally accepted medium of exchange. Property 3, however, is not an indispensable function of money as we have de ned it. Though the money unit is usually used as the unit of account in which prices are quoted, this function of money is conceptually distinct from the other two functions and has sometimes been distinct in practice. During times of high ination, foreign currency has been used as a unit of account, whereas the local money continued to be used as the medium of exchange. During the German hyperination of 1922-23 US dollars were the unit of account used in parts of the economy, whereas the mark was the medium of exchange; and during the Russian hyperination in the middle of the 1990s again US dollars were often the unit of account, but the rouble was still the medium of exchange. This is not to say that it is of little importance that money usually serves as numeraire. Indeed, this function of money plays an important role for the c Groth, Lecture notes in macroeconomics, (mimeo) 2015.
no reviews yet
Please Login to review.