160x Filetype PDF File size 0.04 MB Source: www.uio.no
ECON 4910 Environmental Economics Summary of first five lectures Private and public goods/bads Two goods (or one good and one bad): eg= ()yor yf= ()e f ′ < 0if e is a good f ′ > 0 if e is a bad Two consumers: yy=+y 12 ee=+eif e is a private good/bad 12 Preferences: uy(,e)if eis a private good/bad iii uy,e if eis a public good/bad () ii u >0 if eis a good ie u <0 if eis a bad ie Pareto efficiency: e is a private good: uu 12ee′ ==−f uu 12yy e is a public good: uu 12ee′ +=−f uu 12yy Competitive equilibrium gives Pareto efficiency when e is a private good/bad. If e is a private good/bad and f ′′ < 0, any Pareto efficient outcome can be achieved through a competitive market. Public (non-rival) good may be excludable or non-excludable. Markets may provide excludable public goods, but typically not in an efficient manner. Pollution is a non-excludable bad, and cannot be handled efficiently by markets. - 1 - Money measure of environmental damage De() Define by uy+=De,(e uy,0) () () ′ −ue De()=>0 uy ′′ De()≥0 if preferences are convex (i.e. if u is a quasiconcave function) Efficient negotiations and property rights Income (producer): f (e) Environmental cost (consumer): De( ) Social welfare: f eD− e () () e∗maximizes social welfare, and is achieved through negotiations if no transaction costs or other obstacles. Negotiated level of pollution independent of property rights, but property rights matter for the distribution of net benefits between the producer and the consumer. In reality several obstacles: - transaction costs - free riding - unstable conditions More on f e () f e = reduced form income function, defined by () f ()eF=−max (vq) vG(v)=e v { } where v is an input vector and q is the associated price vector. 0 00 Unconstrained maximization gives v and yf= e. ( ) Constrained maximization: ′ Fq− ′ kk fe= (same for all k ) () ′ G k ′ 0 ′ fe()=0 since Fq= at unconstrained optimum. kk Optimal pollution De()=∑hD()e = aggregate environmental cost h Social welfare = f (eD) − (e) where ee= ∑i ii ∑i Optimum (for interior solution): ∗∗∗ ′′ ′ == = f ()ef... ()eD()e 11 nn - 2 - First n−1 equations are conditions for cost-effectiveness, which also may be defined by f ef==max (e) ee () { } ∑∑ ii i ii It follows from the first order conditions and the envelope theorem that ′ ′′ f (ef) ==(e) ... =f(e) 11 nn Environmental regulation Types of regulation: (a) direct regulation of emissions (b) emission tax (c) tradable quotas (d) subsidies to abatement (e) direct regulation of the producers` input choices (a) direct regulation of emissions ∗∗ ee,..., - to achieve the regulator must know all functions f (e ) () 1 n ii - optimal emissions will generally vary across firms, such regulation may be considered unfair (b) emission tax Producer j: gives f ′ et= max f (et)− e ( ) jj j jj ′ ∗ ′ ∗ ∗ ′ ∗ so cost-effectiveness achieved, also f (eD) = (e)if (tD= e) (c) tradable quotas Producer j: max f (eq)−−(ee) i.e. max f (eq)−+eqe jj jj jj j j gives f ′()eq= (where q is quota price) jj (d) abatement subsidy Producer j: 0 0 max f (es)+−(ee)i.e. max f (es)−+ese jj jj jj j j gives f ′()es= (where s is subsidy rate) jj Note similarity with emission tax and in particular with free tradable quotas (e) direct regulation of vj . i - income = f ()ef< ()e j jjj i - f j not equalized across firms Note: Incentives for new firms to enter market differ between the alternative regulations! - 3 - Complications: - non-convex technologies - asymmetric information Non-convex technologies Simple example: Producer(s) can choose between y=f(e) with same properties as before or zero-emissions 0 technology giving income Y where f(0)
no reviews yet
Please Login to review.