jagomart
digital resources
picture1_Behavioral Economics Pdf 128030 | 95919624


 132x       Filetype PDF       File size 1.82 MB       Source: dash.harvard.edu


File: Behavioral Economics Pdf 128030 | 95919624
principles of behavioral economics citation laibson david and john a list 2015 principles of behavioral economics american economic review 105 5 may 385 390 doi 10 1257 aer p20151047 published ...

icon picture PDF Filetype PDF | Posted on 13 Oct 2022 | 3 years ago
Partial capture of text on file.
     Principles of (Behavioral) Economics
     Citation
     Laibson, David, and John A. List. 2015. “Principles of (Behavioral) Economics.” American 
     Economic Review 105 (5) (May): 385–390. doi:10.1257/aer.p20151047.
     Published Version
     doi:10.1257/aer.p20151047
     Permanent link
     http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:30805504
     Terms of Use
     This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available 
     under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at http://
     nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of-use#LAA
     Share Your Story
     The Harvard community has made this article openly available.
     Please share how this access benefits you.  Submit a story .
     Accessibility
         American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2015, 105(5): 385–390
         http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20151047
                                  BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS IN THE CLASSROOM
                                         Principles of (Behavioral) Economics†
                                                 By David Laibson and John A. List*
                  There are many great ways to incorporate                      Our choice of content for a behavioral lecture 
               behavioral economics in a first-year under-                   is motivated by three factors. First, we include 
               graduate economics class—i.e., the course that                ideas that are conceptually important. Second, 
               is typically called “Principles of Economics.”                we include material that is practically import-
               Our preferred approach integrates behavioral                  ant and personally relevant to our students—we 
               economics  throughout the course (e.g., see                   have found that such content resonates long after 
               Acemoglu, Laibson, and List 2015). With the                   the course ends. Third, we include content that 
               integrated approach, behavioral content plays                 relates to what has been (or will be) taught in the 
               a role in many of the chapters of the principles              rest of the course, and therefore serves as a com-
               of economics curriculum, including chapters on                plement. We want students to see that behavioral 
               optimization, equilibrium, game theory, inter-                economics is an integrated part of economics, not 
               temporal choice, probability and risk, social                 a freak show that is isolated from “the standard 
               preferences, household finance, the labor mar-                ingredients” in the rest of the economics course.
               ket, financial intermediation, monetary policy,                  This paper summarizes our approach to such 
               economic fluctuations, and financial crises.                  a focused behavioral lecture. In Section I, we 
                  We prefer the integrated approach because it               define behavioral economics and place it in his-
               enables the behavioral insights to show up where              torical context. In Section II, we introduce six 
               they are conceptually most relevant. By illustra-             modular principles that can be used to teach 
               tion, it is best to combine a discussion of down-             behavioral economics. We provide PowerPoint 
               ward nominal wage rigidity (i.e., the idea that               notes on our home pages, which instructors 
               workers strongly resist nominal wage declines)                should feel free to edit and use.
               with the overall discussion of the labor market.
                  Whether or not an instructor integrates behav-                       I.  Behavioral Economics Defined
               ioral economics throughout the principles of 
               economics course, it makes sense to pull cen-                    Behavioral economics uses variants of tradi-
               tral materials together and dedicate a lecture                tional economic assumptions (often with a psy-
               (or more) to a focused discussion of behavioral               chological motivation)  to explain and predict 
               economics. This note describes our approach to                behavior, and to provide policy prescriptions.
               such a lecture, emphasizing six key principles of 
               behavioral economics.                                            When we teach our students this definition 
                                                                             of behavioral economics, we like to emphasize 
                                                                             that behavioral economics is a series of amend-
                  * Laibson: Department of Economics, Harvard  ments to, not a rejection of, traditional econom-
               University, Cambridge, MA 02138 and NBER (e-mail:             ics. We illustrate the complementarities between 
               dlaibson@harvard.edu); List: University of Chicago, 1126      traditional and behavioral economics with an 
               E. 59th Street, Chicago, IL 60637 and NBER (e-mail:           example: if you want to get from Chicago to the 
               jlist@uchicago.edu). We thank Saurabh Bhargava, Brigitte      bleachers of Fenway Park to watch the Boston 
               Madrian, and Ted O’Donoghue for helpful suggestions and 
               feedback. We are also grateful to Daron Acemoglu, who         Red Sox, standard economics will get you to 
               directly contributed, as our Economics coauthor, to many of   Cambridge, or even Boston University (which is 
               the pedagogical approaches discussed here.                    adjacent to Fenway), but you may need behav-
                  † Go to http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20151047 to visit 
               the article page for additional materials and author disclo-  ioral economics to take the final steps and find 
               sure statement(s).                                            your seat in the bleachers.
                                                                         385
             386                             AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS                                 MAY 2015
                In this way, behavioral economics augments       PRINCIPLE 1: People try to choose the best fea-
             standard economic analysis. Behavioral eco-         sible option, but they sometimes don’t succeed.
             nomics adopts and refines the three core prin-        In other words, people try to make the optimal 
             ciples of economics: optimization, equilibrium,     choice—they are optimizers—but they some-
             and empiricism (Acemoglu, Laibson, and List         times make mistakes. It’s important to empha-
             2015). Both traditional and behavioral econo-       size that these mistakes are partially predictable. 
             mists believe that (i) people try to choose their   One of the key explanatory factors is experi-
             best feasible option (optimization); (ii) people    ence and training: experienced decision-makers 
             try to choose their best feasible option when       tend to make better choices than inexperienced 
             interacting with others (equilibrium); and (iii)    decision-makers.
             models need to be tested with data (empiricism).      To illustrate these ideas, we use a range of 
             In the next section we provide some examples        examples. If students play the p-beauty contest 
             of how behavioral economics refines economic        game twice, they will see behavior converging 
             analysis.                                           toward the Nash equilibrium. The game is sim-
                From a historical perspective, the big bang      ple enough to be played in class (or on the web 
             for behavioral economics was a paper on pref-       before class). But even if you don’t actually play 
             erences over gambles written by two psycholo-       the game in class, you’ll be able to show the stu-
             gists, Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, in         dents easy to understand data (e.g., Nagel 1995) 
             1979. So modern behavioral economics is a lot       that illustrates this convergence.
             younger than the rest of the field of economics.      If you prefer to teach the first principle using 
                However, behavioral concepts have always         field data, you could explain that credit card 
             played a part in economic analysis (though          users pay fewer and fewer fees—for instance, 
             they didn’t always have that headline name).        late payment fees—the more experience they 
             As Ashraf, Camerer, and Loewenstein (2005)          have with their card (Agarwal et al. 2013). 
             point out, Adam Smith frequently wrote about        Likewise, consumers switch telephone plans, 
             the psychology of decision-making, including        moving toward the best one, as they gain experi-
             the tension between a person’s “passions” and       ence (Miravete 2003).
             their rational deliberations, which Smith refers      These examples all illustrate that “everyone 
             to as the “impartial spectator.” The impar-         choosing optimally” is a better prediction for 
             tial spectator is the source of “self-denial, of    experienced decision-makers than for inexperi-
             self-government, of that command of the pas-        enced decision-makers.
             sions which subjects all the movements of our         The first principle should also be used to 
             nature to what our own dignity and honour,          explain why learning economics is so useful 
             and the propriety of our own conduct require”       to students. Economics courses have the tan-
             (Smith 1759 [1984], I, i, v, 23). Psychological     gible benefit of increasing the optimality of 
             assumptions are as old as economics itself.         the students’ own decisions. We tell our stu-
                                                                 dents that “learning economics turns you into a 
                                                                  decision-maker who is more likely to choose the 
                II.  Six Principles of Behavioral Economics      best feasible alternative. By taking economics, 
                                                                 you become a more skilled optimizer.”
                These principles are modular, so instructors 
             can pick whatever subset matches their interests    PRINCIPLE 2: People care (in part) about how 
             and their time budget. In our experience, all six   their circumstances compare to reference points. 
             principles can be covered in a 1.5 hour lecture,      For example, a reference point could be the 
             but that is not what we recommend. If you wish      amount of money a person expected to earn 
             to cover all six principles, we suggest allotting   during summer break, or the amount of money 
             two lectures.                                       that she started with when she entered a casino, or 
                After each principle we present a series of      the price she paid for 100 shares of Apple stock, or 
             examples that illustrate and explain the princi-    the price she paid for her home. It matters whether 
             ple and engage first-year economics students.       a person is losing or gaining relative to their refer-
             We’ve included more examples than you will          ence point. Losses get far more weight than gains, 
             probably be able to use, so we encourage you to     which is called loss aversion (Kahneman and 
             pick among them.                                    Tversky 1979). In practice,  people suffer from a 
              VOL. 105 NO. 5                          PRINCIPLES OF (BEHAVIORAL) ECONOMICS                               387
              loss about twice as much as they benefit from a              Fun evidence-based examples include post-
              gain of equal absolute magnitude.                         poning planned work tasks (Augenblick, 
                 These phenomena have implications for  Niederle, and Sprenger 2014), placing savings 
              market transactions. Loss aversion discourages            in a lockbox (Ashraf, Karlan, and Yin 2006; 
              trade, since each trade generates two losses and          Beshears et al. 2013), workplace productivity 
              two gains (the buyer has a loss and a gain and            commitments (Kaur, Kremer, and Mullainathan 
              the seller has a loss and a gain), and the losses         forthcoming), and committing to not smoke 
              are weighted more than the gains. Accordingly,            cigarettes or drink alcohol (Giné, Karlan, and 
              people are prone to hold on to their endowments           Zinman 2010; Schilbach 2015). Controlling for 
              (Thaler 1980).                                            time of day, Read and van Leeuwen (1998) show 
                 There are many ways to illustrate this endow-          that snacks chosen in advance are overwhelm-
              ment effect. For example, give half of your stu-          ingly healthy, but snacks chosen for immediate 
              dents a mug and half of your students a (big)             consumption are not.
              chocolate bar, randomizing this endowment by 
              switching every other seat in the classroom. Let          PRINCIPLE 4: Although we mostly care about 
              the students examine their own and their neigh-           our own material payoffs, we also care about the 
              bors’ endowments, and then ask the class who              actions, intentions, and payoffs of others, even 
              wants to trade with you for the good that they            people outside our family. 
              didn’t receive. Fewer than a quarter of the stu-             These “social preferences” come in many sys-
              dents will take up this offer, but traditional eco-       tematic forms, especially negative reciprocity, 
              nomic theory predicts that half of them should            behindness aversion, and social pressure.
              (Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler 1990; Tversky                 One way to teach these ideas is to play the 
              and Kahneman 1991).                                       ultimatum game (Güth, Schmittberger, and 
                 If you wish to go deeper, show your students           Schwarze 1982). An anonymous sender and 
              that market experience reduces the endowment              an anonymous recipient are paired. The sender 
              effect (e.g., List 2003). Or show them how fram-          divides an endowment of $10 (any division is 
              ing manipulations that exploit loss aversion can          allowed, rounded off to the nearest penny). The 
              be used to incent workers to be more produc-              recipient either accepts or rejects the division. 
              tive  (e.g., Hossain and List 2012). You could            In the event of rejection, both players go home 
              also show your class loss aversion in gambles:            empty-handed. Most senders propose a division 
              people won’t take an even odds gamble unless              in which the recipient receives at least $2.00, 
              the upside has twice the reward as the downside           because the senders correctly anticipate that half 
              (Kahneman and Tversky 1979).                              of the recipients will retaliate against an offer 
                                                                        that is less generous than this (even though the 
              PRINCIPLE 3: People have self-control  retaliation hurts the recipient).
              problems.                                                    Such social preferences respond to incen-
                 In a traditional economic model there is no            tives, just like all other economic decisions. As 
              gap between a person’s good intentions and                the stakes get large, the recipient becomes more 
              their actions. By contrast, in the model of pres-         and more willing to accept unfair offers. For 
              ent bias, people plan to work hard (or diet, or           example, Andersen et al. (2011) find that when 
              exercise, or quit smoking, or save for retirement,        the pot to be divided is nearly a year’s wages, 
              or stop borrowing on their credit card, etc.) and         almost no recipients reject a 20 percent offer 
              then renege at the last second (Laibson 1997;             from the sender. Showing students that prices 
              O’Donoghue and Rabin 1999).                               matter in the domain of social preferences helps 
                 Instructors can show how the present-biased            them develop a deeper understanding of both 
              discount function {1, ½, ½, ½, … } leads to pref-         social preferences and the traditional model.
              erence reversals if studying has an immediate 
              effort cost of 6 and a delayed benefit of 8. In this      PRINCIPLE 5: Sometimes market exchange 
              case, studying tomorrow looks good in the eyes            makes psychological factors cease to matter, 
              of the student because ½ × [−6 + 8] = 1 > 0,              but many psychological factors matter even in 
              but immediate studying does not (because                  markets. 
              −6 + ½ × 8 = −2 < 0). In this simple exam-                   If investors with behavioral biases are a small 
              ple, studying never takes place.                          part of the total stock market, their beliefs will 
The words contained in this file might help you see if this file matches what you are looking for:

...Principles of behavioral economics citation laibson david and john a list american economic review may doi aer p published version permanent link http nrs harvard edu urn hul instrepos terms use this article was downloaded from university s dash repository is made available under the conditions applicable to other posted material as set forth at current laa share your story community has openly please how access benefits you submit accessibility papers proceedings dx org in classroom by there are many great ways incorporate our choice content for lecture first year motivated three factors we include graduate class i e course that ideas conceptually important second typically called practically import preferred approach integrates ant personally relevant students throughout g see have found such resonates long after acemoglu with ends third integrated plays relates what been or will be taught role chapters rest therefore serves com curriculum including on plement want optimization equil...

no reviews yet
Please Login to review.