163x Filetype PDF File size 2.43 MB Source: g2lm-lic.iza.org
WP GLM|LIC Working Paper No. 20 | August 2016 Comparative Advantage, International Trade, and Fertility Quy-Toan Do (The World Bank) Andrei A. Levchenko (University of Michigan, NBER, CEPR and IZA) Claudio Raddatz (Central Bank of Chile) GLM|LIC Working Paper No. 20 | August 2016 Comparative Advantage, International Trade, and Fertility Quy-Toan Do (The World Bank) Andrei A. Levchenko (University of Michigan, NBER, CEPR and IZA) Claudio Raddatz (Central Bank of Chile) GLM|LIC c/o IZA – Institute of Labor Economics Schaumburg-Lippe-Straße 5–9 53113 Bonn, Germany Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-510 Email: glm-review@iza.org GLM|LIC Working Paper No. 20 | August 2016 ABSTRACT Comparative Advantage, International Trade, and Fertility* We analyze theoretically and empirically the impact of comparative advantage in international trade on fertility. We build a model in which industries differ in the extent to which they use female relative to male labor, and countries are characterized by Ricardian comparative advantage in either female-labor or male- labor intensive goods. The main prediction of the model is that countries with comparative advantage in female-labor intensive goods are characterized by lower fertility. This is because female wages, and therefore the opportunity cost of children are higher in those countries. We demonstrate empirically that countries with comparative advantage in industries employing primarily women exhibit lower fertility. We use a geography- based instrument for trade patterns to isolate the causal effect of comparative advantage on fertility. JEL Classification: F16, J13, O11 Keywords: fertility, trade integration, comparative advantage Corresponding author: Andrei A. Levchenko University of Michigan 611 Tappan Street Ann Arbor, MI 48109 USA E-mail: alev@umich.edu * We are grateful to Raj Arunachalam, Martha Bailey, Francesco Caselli, Francisco Ferreira, Elisa Gamberoni, Gene Grossman, David Lam, Carolina Sanchez-Paramo, and seminar participants at various institutions for helpful suggestions. Çăgatay Bircan, Aaron Flaaen, Dimitrije Ruzic, and Nitya Pandalai Nayar provided outstanding research assistance. The project has been funded in part by the World Bank’s Research Support Budget. The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors and need not represent either the views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors or the countries they represent, or those of the Central Bank of Chile or the members of its board. This document is an output from a project funded by the UK Department for International Development (DFID) and the Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) for the benefit of developing countries. The views expressed are not necessarily those of DFID or IZA. 1 Introduction Attempts to understand population growth and the determinants of fertility date as far back as Thomas Malthus. Postulating that fertility decisions are influenced by women’s oppor- tunity cost of time (Becker, 1960), choice over fertility has been incorporated into growth models in order to understand the joint behavior of population and economic development throughout history (see e.g. Barro and Becker 1989; Becker et al. 1990; Kremer 1993; Galor and Weil 1996, 2000; Greenwood and Seshadri 2002; Doepke 2004; Doepke et al. 2007; Jones and Tertilt 2008). The large majority of existing analyses examine individual countries in a closed-economy setting. However, in an era of ever-increasing integration of world markets, the role of globalization in determining fertility can no longer be ignored. This paper studies both theoretically and empirically the impact of comparative advan- tage in international trade on fertility outcomes. Our conceptual framework is based on three assumptions. First, goods di↵er in the intensity of female labor: some industries em- ploy primarily women, others primarily men. This assumption is standard in theories of gender and the labor market Galor and Weil (1996); Black and Juhn (2000); Qian (2008); Black and Spitz-Oener (2010); Rendall (2010); Pitt et al. (2012); Alesina et al. (2013), and as we show below finds ample support in the data. In the rest of the paper, we refer to goods that employ primarily (fe)male labor as the (fe)male-intensive goods. Second, women bear a disproportionate burden of raising children. That is, a child reduces a woman’s labor market supply more than a man’s. This assumption is also well-accepted (Becker, 1981, 1985; Galor and Weil, 2000), and is consistent with a great deal of empirical evidence (see, e.g., Angrist and Evans, 1998; Guryan et al., 2008). Finally, di↵erences in technologies and resource en- dowments imply that some countries have a comparative advantage in the female-intensive goods, and others in the male-intensive goods. Our paper is the first to both provide em- pirical evidence that countries indeed di↵er in the gender composition of their comparative advantage, and to explore the impact of comparative advantage in international trade on fertility in a broad sample of countries. The main theoretical result is that countries with comparative advantage in female- intensive goods exhibit lower fertility. The result thus combines Becker’s hypothesis that fertility is a↵ected by women’s opportunity cost of time with the insight that this opportu- nity cost is higher in countries with a comparative advantage in female-intensive industries. Wethen provide empirical evidence for the main prediction of the model using industry- level export data for 61 manufacturing sectors in 145 developed and developing countries over 5 decades. We use sector-level data on the share of female workers in total employment to classify sectors as female- and male- intensive. The variation across sectors in the share 1
no reviews yet
Please Login to review.