138x Filetype PDF File size 0.19 MB Source: core.ac.uk
The Role of Inventories In the Business Cycle BY AUBHIK KHAN hanges in the stock of firms’ inventories are INVENTORIES SEEM an important component of the business TO BE IMPORTANT IN THE C BUSINESS CYCLE cycle. In fact, discussion about the timing Figure 1 shows the business- of a recovery following economic recessions cycle component of real gross domestic product (GDP) in the United States often focuses on inventories. Aubhik Khan surveys the over most of the postwar period. We can facts about inventory investment over the business think of movements in GDP as the sum of two components: the trend and the cycle, then discusses two leading theories that may business cycle. The trend represents the explain these observations. average growth rate of the economy across surrounding years. The business cycle reflects short-term deviations from this trend: the expansions and contrac- 1 2 tions that make up the business cycle. , Changes in the stock of firms’ that may explain these observations. For comparison, recessions, as dated by inventories are an important component Theory that passes the test of observa- the National Bureau of Economic of the business cycle. Alan Blinder, a tion may allow us, with some confi- Research, are shaded in the figure. former Governor of the Federal Reserve dence, to predict future movements in The figure also includes System, famously remarked that “the the data. Theories that have sought to changes in the stock of private nonfarm business cycle, to a surprisingly large explain macroeconomic changes in inventories (private refers to nongovern- degree, is an inventory cycle.” Consis- inventory investment have generally ment). The difference between GDP, tent with this perspective, much of the focused on firms’ attempts to (1) reduce the sum of all goods and services discussion about the timing of a the costs of adjusting their production produced in the economy over a given recovery following economic recessions level or (2) reduce the costs of placing period, and final sales, the sum of all focuses on firms’ stocks of inventories. orders for intermediate goods. While goods and services sold, is known as net Pundits suggest that production and much of the research on inventories in inventory investment. Net inventory employment cannot recover until firms’ the past 50 years has emphasized the inventories fall, relative to their sales. cost of adjusting production, this This article surveys the facts approach has had well-known difficul- about inventory investment over the ties when confronted with the data. 1 Actually, any type of expenditure or output business cycle, then discusses two Recent work that has focused on may be broken down into a business-cycle component and a trend. The process of leading theories of inventory investment reducing the fixed costs of ordering isolating the business-cycle component is goods may provide a framework that is known as “detrending” or “filtering.” The real quarterly series in the figure have been more consistent with the facts. At the detrended with the Hodrick-Prescott filter same time, this recent work may using a smoothing parameter of 1600. For produce new insights about the additional details, see Edward C. Prescott’s paper. Aubhik Khan is a interaction between inventories and the macroeconomy. These two theories 2 It then follows that a recession, in this senior economist in approach to business cycles, is a period in the Research predict different behavior for aggregate which the economy is growing at rates that Department of the production, sales, and inventory are lower than its trend. This contrasts with Philadelphia Fed. investment. the conventional use of the term recession to describe a period of negative growth. 38 Q3 2003 Business Review www.phil.frb.org investment is a measure of goods that sures the size of the variable’s total that a common view of inventories — 3 have been made but not sold to fluctuation over the business cycle. that they are goods that firms were consumers nor used by a firm as an Economic variables differ considerably unable to sell — can’t explain most of intermediate input into production. in their volatility. For example, consump- the movements in inventories. In an A car made by Honda in Ohio, tion of nondurable goods and services is expansion, inventories grow as consump- completed but retained unused in the far less volatile than GDP, while business tion and investment grow. That is, when factory, adds to Honda’s stock of investment and consumption of sales rise, inventories also rise. If inventories. Steel bought by the same consumer durable goods are more inventories were mainly goods that firms manufacturer but left unused is a raw volatile — i.e., they have bigger swings. couldn’t sell, they would tend to rise material that also adds to Honda’s stock Thus, investment fluctuates a lot more when sales fell. of inventories. Nonfarm private than does the consumption of nondu- By definition GDP = Final inventories are essentially stocks of these rables and services as output rises and Sales + Net Inventory Investment. final goods, intermediate inputs, falls. Thus, any change in GDP must be materials, or supplies held by businesses. Net inventory investment is attributable to either a change in final Changes in this component of total pro-cyclical (Figure 1). It moves along sales or a change in net inventory inventory investment account for most with GDP, rising during expansions and investment. Let’s look at the fraction of of the change in total inventories over falling during recessions. This is a very the change in GDP that can be the business cycle. important observation because it means accounted for by changes in net Cyclicality and Volatility. In inventory investment. To accomplish organizing their thinking about the role this, we divide the change in inventories of an economic variable such as during recessions by the corresponding inventory investment over the business 3 Formally, we define volatility as the change in GDP. The result is a number cycle, economists focus on the cyclicality standard deviation of the business-cycle around one-half. Almost half of the fall component of the quarterly data. and volatility of the variable. A variable’s cyclicality — formally, its correlation with real GDP — is a measure of how the variable changes FIGURE 1 over the business cycle. For example, net exports — that is, exports minus imports GDP, Final Sales, and Changes in Nonfarm In- — are countercyclical: they fall as GDP ventories rises during an expansion, and they rise as GDP declines in a recession. In contrast, consumption and investment are pro-cyclical: they rise during expansions and fall, alongside GDP, in recessions. A significant correlation, whether positive or negative, between any economic variable and GDP suggests that the variable is cyclical in that it varies in a systematic way with GDP over the business cycle. This is not true of all economic variables. For example, government spending is acyclical: it shows no significant correlation with economy activity over the business cycle, neither rising nor falling systematically. While the cyclicality of a variable measures the extent to which it rises or falls with GDP, volatility mea- www.phil.frb.org Business Review Q3 2003 39 in production experienced by the U.S. THE MYSTERY known as the (S, s) model of inventories, economy during a recession may be OF INVENTORIES emphasizes the costs of accepting explained by a reduction in net Economists are not satisfied deliveries. While each of these theories inventory investment. This is a merely to uncover the facts about can explain why firms hold inventories, surprisingly large fraction when one inventories and the business cycle. they are commonly applied to different considers that net inventory investment Their primary goal is to explain these types of inventories. Thus, the two is, on average, only around 0.5 percent findings. Before we may begin to theories are not mutually exclusive; both of GDP. It indicates that inventory understand why firms change their may be relevant to an understanding of investment is extremely volatile. holdings of inventories over the business the overall stock of inventories. Adding to the Volatility of cycle, we must have an understanding However, as with all science, Output. The pro-cyclicality and of why firms hold inventories at all. For the empirical relevance of these extreme volatility of inventory invest- economic theory, this has been more of a alternative theories can be assessed by ment have led researchers to suggest mystery than you might suppose. evaluating their predictions against the that inventories are a destabilizing force. Why would a firm produce data. The production-smoothing model At its simplest, their argument is as goods but not sell them? Sales com- and the (S, s) model generally have follows. Inventory investment and final pleted today give the firm income that it distinct predictions about the joint sales tend to move together: both rise may invest. For example, even if the behavior of production, sales, and during expansions, and both fall during firm has no other immediate use for the inventory investment. recessions. Consequently, GDP varies funds, it might deposit them in an by more than it would if inventory interest-earning account. A firm would THE PRODUCTION- investment were constant or negatively forgo this interest income if it chooses SMOOTHING MODEL correlated with final sales. not to sell its goods immediately. The production-smoothing To understand this better, But perhaps it isn’t voluntary. model explains why a manufacturing consider the following simple example. If You may think firms hold inventories firm holds stocks of goods produced but final sales rise during odd years and fall only of finished goods they have been unsold. The model assumes that it is during even years, while inventory unable to sell. While firms do sometimes costly for the manufacturing firm to investment rises (by the same amount) accumulate inventories of unsold goods adjust production. during even years and falls during odd because of weaker-than-expected It is costly to buy and install years, there’s no effect on GDP. demand, this can’t be the central new equipment or to uninstall and sell Inventory investment and final sales explanation of inventory holdings. First, off previously installed equipment. move in opposite directions; they are remember that inventories rise when Workers are costly to hire and train, and negatively correlated. As a result, each sales do. Second, goods that have been layoffs are also expensive. Since chang- offsets the change in the other. Produc- produced but not yet sold are only a ing levels of output often involve tion is smoothed. fraction of the total stock of inventories. changing the size of the labor force and Now, consider an alternative Firms also hold inventories of inputs they purchasing new capital equipment, case in which both series rise during odd use to produce their goods, buying them these adjustment costs are inevitable for a years. Since inventory investment moves before they need them. firm that changes its level of output over with output, and since it’s highly The answer to the question of time. It’s reasonable to assume that these volatile, inventories substantially raise why firms forgo interest income must costs of changing production levels the volatility of GDP. Since final sales involve benefits derived from holding actually increase with the size of the and inventory investment are indeed inventories. Holding stocks of invento- change. For example, a large increase in positively correlated, typically rising and ries must somehow reduce a firm’s cost production requires hiring more workers falling at the same time, researchers of production, and these cost savings and, thus, involves higher training costs. have concluded that inventories are a must exceed the forgone interest. In any case, given these costs of adjust- destabilizing force in the economy. (See There are two theories of how ing production, if sales are volatile, a Are Inventories Becoming Less Promi- production costs induce firms to hold firm may prefer not to vary production nent?) Changes in inventories magnify stocks of inventories. The first, known to match the variation in sales. Instead, the effect of a change in final sales on as the production-smoothing model of it may use inventories of already domestic production. inventories, emphasizes the costs of produced goods to offset the difference adjusting production. The second, between production and sales. 40 Q3 2003 Business Review www.phil.frb.org ARE INVENTORIES BECOMING LESS PROMINENT? If inventories are indeed a destabilizing element intermediate inputs and materials and supplies, both of aggregate economic activity, perhaps the much heralded components of the overall stock of inventories but not part improvements in technology that have led to sharp declines of final sales, must account for the divergence between the in the inventory to sales ratio will eventually yield a less real and nominal ratios of inventories to sales. severe business cycle. Since inventories seem to explain so While I cannot suggest which ratio is more much of the decline in output during recessions, and since sensible, Figure 2 casts some doubt on some of the discus- they amplify the effect of changes in final sales on GDP, as sion of technological improvements’ role in reducing inventory levels decline, perhaps GDP will be subject to less demand for inventories. While both the financial press and severe fluctuations. policymakers have repeatedly mentioned the important Arguments such as this have led economists to role of improved management techniques, such as just-in- emphasize the decline in the inventory to sales ratio. In time production methods, in reducing firms’ dependence Figure 2, we see the nominal stock of inventories as a ratio on inventories, the real inventory to sales ratio in Figure 2 of final sales. Clearly, it has declined sharply since the early suggests caution before making sweeping generalizations. 1980s. Many observers have regarded this decline as the When examining the nominal inventory to sales ratio, we result of improvements in technology and management see that it rose before it fell, something that is hard to methods that have allowed firms to reduce their holdings explain using technological improvement. The real ratio of inventories relative to their sales. This is less clear from has not declined consistently over the past 20 years. the figure. First, we see that the inventory to sales ratio rose sharply in the 1970s. If technological FIGURE 2 innovation has reduced the ratio since the 1980s, what was the sharp Quarterly Nominal and Real Inventory technological regress in the 1970s? to Sales Ratios Second, and related, is the finding that the inventory to sales ratio was as low in the late 1960s as it was in the mid 1980s. Even the decline in the importance of inventories is less clear than is commonly acknowledged. The figure also plots the real inventory to sales ratio, that is, the ratio when both inventories and sales figures have been divided by their price indexes. While the nominal inventory to sales ratio shows a clear negative trend over the past 20 to 25 years, the real inventory to sales ratio displays no corresponding decline! This implies that the price index for inventories has fallen more slowly than that for final sales. It would seem that changes in the relative price of www.phil.frb.org Business Review Q3 2003 41
no reviews yet
Please Login to review.