jagomart
digital resources
picture1_Economics Pdf 125551 | 01dnotes


 160x       Filetype PDF       File size 0.37 MB       Source: pages.nyu.edu


File: Economics Pdf 125551 | 01dnotes
notes for a course in development economics debraj ray version 2 3 2001 1 introduction open a book any book on the economics of developing countries and it will begin ...

icon picture PDF Filetype PDF | Posted on 11 Oct 2022 | 3 years ago
Partial capture of text on file.
                                Notes for a Course in Development Economics
                                                             Debraj Ray
                                                            Version 2.3, 2001.
                    1 Introduction
                    Open a book — any book —on the economics of developing countries, and it will begin with
                    the usual litany of woes. Developing countries, notwithstanding the enormous strides they
                    have made in the last few decades, display fundamental economic inadequacies in a wide
                    range of indicators. Levels of physical capital per person are small. Nutrition levels are low.
                    Other indicators of human capital such as education — both at the primary and seconday
                    levels — are well below developed-country benchmarks. So are access to sanitation, safe
                    water and housing. Population growth rates are high, and so are infant mortality rates. One
                    could expand this list indefinitely.
                        Notice that some of these indicators — infant mortality or life expectancy, for instance —
                    may be regarded as defining features of underdevelopment, so in this respect the list above
                    maybeviewed, not as a statement of correlations, but as a definition of what we mean by de-
                    velopment (or the lack of it). But other indicators, such as low quantities of physical capital
                    per capita, or population growth rates, are at least one step removed. These features don’t
                    define underdevelopment. For instance, it is unclear whether low fertility rates are intrinsi-
                    cally a feature of economic welfare or development. Surely, many families in rich countries
                    may take great pleasure in having a large number of offspring. Likewise, large holdings of
                    physical capital may well have an instrumental value to play in the development process,
                    but surely the mere existence of such holdings does not constitute a defining characteristic
                    of economic welfare.
                        And indeed, that is how it should be. We do not make a list of the features that go
                    hand in hand with underdevelopment simply to define the term. We do so because —
                    implictly or explicitly — we are looking for explanations. Why are underdeveloped countries
                                      1
                    underdeveloped?      It is easy enough to point to these inadequacies in terms of physical
                    and human capital, but the extra step to branding these as causes of underdevelopment is
                    perilously close, and we should avoid taking that step. Low levels of capital, or low levels of
                    education, are just as much symptoms of development as causes, and to the extent that they
                    intertwine with and accompany the development process (or the lack of it), we cannot rely
                    on these observations as explanations.
                       1Perhaps the word “underdeveloped” does not constitute politically correct usuage, so that several pub-
                    lications — those by well-known international organizations chief among them — use the somewhat more
                    hopeful and placatory present continuous “developing”. I won’t be using such niceties in this article, because
                    it should be clear — or at least it is clear in my mind — that economic underdevelopment pins no derogatory
                    social label on those who live in, or come from, such societies.
                                                                    1
                         That doesn’t stop economists from offering such explanations, however. More than one
                     influential study has regressed growth rates (alternatively, levels) of per-capita income on
                     variables such as the rate of savings and population growth. There is very little doubt, in
                     fact, that such variables are significantly associated with per-capita income? But neverthe-
                     less, we do have to think about the sense in which these studies serve as explanations for
                     underdevelopment.
                         For instance, is it the case that individuals in different parts of the world have some
                     intrinsic difference in their willingness — or ability — to save, or to procreate? If this were
                     the case, we could hang our hat on the following sort of theory: such-and-such country is
                     populated by people who habitually save very little. This is why they are underdeveloped.
                         Somehow, this does not seem right. We would like to have a theory which — while not
                     belittling or downplaying the role of social, cultural and political factors — does not simply
                     stop there. We would like to know, for instance, whether low incomes provoke, in turn,
                     low savings rates so that we have a genuine chicken-and-egg problem. The same is true of
                     demographics — might underdevelopment be a cause of high population growth rates, just
                     as high population growth rates themselves retard the development process.
                         Mygoal in this article is to talk about some of these chicken-and-egg situations, in which
                     underdevelopmentisseennotasafailureofsomefundamentaleconomicparameters, orsocio-
                     cultural values, but as an interacting “equilibrium” that hangs together, perhaps precipitated
                     byinertia or by history. [Indeed, in what follows, I will make a conceptual distinction between
                     equilibria created by inertia and those created by history.]
                         Whyis this view of the development process an important one? There are three reasons
                     why I feel this view should be examined very seriously.
                     [1] This point of view leads to a theory, or a set of theories, in which economic “convergence”
                     (of incomes, wealth, levels of well-being) across countries is not to be automatically had.
                     Actually, the intelligent layperson reading these words will find this reasoning a bit abstruse:
                     why on earth would one expect convergence in the first place? And why, indeed, should I
                     find a theory interesting on the grounds that it does not predict convergence, when I knew
                     that all along? This is not a bad line of reasoning, but to appreciate why it is misguided, it is
                     important to refer to a venerable tradition in economics that has convergence as its very core
                     prediction. The idea is based — roughly — on the argument that countries which are poor
                     will have higher marginal products of capital, and consequently a higher rate of return to
                     capital. This means that a dollar of extra savings will have a higher payoff in poor countries,
                     allowing it grow faster. The prediction: pooere countries will tend to grow faster, so that
                     over time rich and poor countries will come together, or “converge”.
                         This is not the place to examine the convergence hypothesis in detail, as my intention is
                                                           2
                     to cover other views of development. But one should notice that convergence theories in this
                     rawformhaverarelybeenfoundacceptable(thoughrarely does not mean never, among some
                     economists), and there are several subtle variants of the theory. Some of these variants still
                     preserve the idea that lots of “other things” being equal, convergence in some conditional
                     sense is still to be had. It’s only if we start accepting the possibility that — perhaps —
                     these “other things” cannot be kept equal, that the notion of conditional convergence starts
                        2See Ray [1998], Chapters 2 and 3.
                                                                     2
                 losing its relevance and very different views of development, not at all based on the idea of
                 convergence, must be sought.
                 [2] The second reason why I find these theories important is that they do not reply on
                 “fundamental” differences across peoples or cultures. Thus we may worry about whether
                 Confucianism is better than the Protestant ethic in promoting hard-headed, succesful eco-
                 nomic agents, and we might certainly decry Hindu fatalism as deeply inimical to purposeful,
                 economic self-advancement, but we have seen again and again that when it comes down
                 to the economic crunch and circumstances are right, both Confucian and Hindu will make
                 the best of available opportunities — and so will the Catholics and a host of other relgions
                 and cultures besides. Once again, this is not the place to examine in detail fundamentalist
                 explanations based on cultural or religious differences, but I simply don’t find them very
                 convincing. This is not to say that culture — like conditional convergence — does not play
                 a role. [In fact, I provide such examples below.] But I also take the view that culture, along
                 with several other economic, social and political institutions, are all part of some broader
                 interactive theory in which “first cause” is to be found — if at all — in historical accident.
                 [3] The last reason why I wish to focus on these theories is that create a very different role for
                 government policy. Specifically, I will argue that these theories place a much greater weight
                 on one-time, or temporary, interventions than theories that are based on fundamentals. For
                 instance, if it is truly Hindu fatalism that keeps Indian savings rates low, then a policy of
                 encouraging savings (say, through tax breaks) will certainly have an effect on growth rates.
                 But there is no telling when that policy can be taken away, or indeed, if it can be taken away
                 at all. For in the absence of the policy, the theory would tell us that savings would revert
                 to the old Hindu level. In contrast, a theory that is based on an interactive chicken-and-egg
                 approach would promote a policy that attempts to push the chicken-egg cycle into a new
                 equilibrium. Once that happens, the policy can be removed. This is not to say that once-
                 and-for-all policies are the correct ones, but only to appreciate that the interactive theories
                 I am going to talk about have very different implications from the traditional ones.
                 2 Complementarities
                 2.1  ADefinition
                 It will suffice for the purpose of these notes to provide a simplified definition. Suppose that
                 a set of individuals all have access to some set of actions A, taken to be a subset of the real
                 line. Denote by a a generic action, a the action taken by individual i, and by m the average
                                               i                                   i
                 of all actions other than the one taken by i.
                    Assumethatthepayofffunctionisgivenbyπi(a,m)foreachindividuali, where a denotes
                 his action and m denotes the average action taken by everybody else. We say that the
                 situation exhibits complementarities if for all i,
                                                    ′
                                       πi(a,m)πi(a,m) is increasing in m                  (1)
                              ′
                 whenever a>a are two actions in the set A.
                                                      3
                    Notice the difference between complementarities and positive externalities. The former
                 change the marginal gain to taking an action while the latter affects payoff levels — the
                 margins can go either way.
                    As we shall see, Pareto-ordered outcomes are typical of these situations (though they
                 won’t necessarily happen).
                 2.2  Some Examples
                 2.2.1 Qwerty
                 There are two technologies; call them [Q]werty and [D]vorak. There are many individuals,
                 each of whom employs a single Q-trained secretary or a single D-trained secretary. The
                 cost of installing each technology is the same, but the cost expended on a secretary is a
                 decreasing function of the number of other people using the same secretary type. [More
                 secretarial schools exist for that type.] Show that this is a situation of complementarities.
                    You could do this also with technologies [P]c and [M]acs, in which the benefits from
                 adopting the technology depend positively on the number of other users (networking).
                 2.2.2 Infrastructure
                 Arailroad is used for transporting products from the interior to the ports. People are indexed
                 on [0,1], and person i gets a benefit B(i) from being able to use the railroad. The cost of
                 railroad use is declining in the number of users: c(n), where n is the number of users and
                 ′
                 c (n) < 0. Show that this is a situation of complementarities.
                 2.2.3 Finance
                 A thicker financial market caused by lots of people putting their money in financial assets
                 can create the possibilities of greater diversification. So at the margin, it becomes easier for
                 an individual investor to invest.
                    The problems at the end of Chapter 5 of DE contain numerous other examples.
                 2.3  Complementarities and Development
                 Theordinaryviewofcapitalistdevelopmentisthatitinflictsnegativeexternalities: pollution,
                 greed and so on. This is certainly true. But there is an important sense in which the capitalist
                 investment process creates severe complementarities (whether the underlying externalities are
                 negative or positive; they could be either).
                    Forinstance, a firm that prides itself on quality and fair dealing will induce its competitors
                 to take the same actions simply to maintain business competitiveness, and could spark off a
                 quality race (the same applies to research and innovation, or indeed, low prices). Note that
                 the underlying externalities are negative but that we have a case of complementarities in the
                 appropriate action space.
                    In another context, the combined actions of several firms can (a) lower infrastructural
                 costs, (b) create demand for each others’ products, both directly and (c) by creating higher
                 incomes; and can (d) enable the creation of new products or the startup of some other
                                                      4
The words contained in this file might help you see if this file matches what you are looking for:

...Notes for a course in development economics debraj ray version introduction open book any on the of developing countries and it will begin with usual litany woes notwithstanding enormous strides they have made last few decades display fundamental economic inadequacies wide range indicators levels physical capital per person are small nutrition low other human such as education both at primary seconday well below developed country benchmarks so access to sanitation safe water housing population growth rates high infant mortality one could expand this list indenitely notice that some these or life expectancy instance may be regarded dening features underdevelopment respect above maybeviewed not statement correlations but denition what we mean by de velopment lack quantities capita least step removed don t dene is unclear whether fertility intrinsi cally feature welfare surely many families rich take great pleasure having large number ospring likewise holdings an instrumental value play p...

no reviews yet
Please Login to review.